Richmond Fed Interview

Richmond Fed Interview

The Richmond Fed published a long interview with me in their Econ Focus, shorter pdf (print) version here and longer web version here. Some of the questions:

  • Does the 2010 Dodd-Frank regulatory reform act meaningfully address runs on shadow banking?
  • So what do you think is the most promising way to meaningfully end “too big to fail”?
  • Do you think there’s any reason to believe recessions following financial crises should necessarily be longer and more severe, as Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff have famously suggested?
  • Many people have asked whether the finance industry has gotten too big. How should we think about that?
  • What are your thoughts on quantitative easing (QE) — the Fed’s massive purchases of Treasuries and other assets to push down long-term interest rates — both on its effectiveness and on the fear that it’s going to lead to hyperinflation?
  • Both fiscal and monetary policies have been on extreme courses recently. What are your thoughts on how they might affect each other as they move back to normal levels?
  • Switching gears to finance specifically, what do you think are some of the big unanswered questions for research?
  • You wrote an op-ed on an “alternative maximum tax.” What’s the idea there?
  • Can transfers really help the bottom half of the income distribution?
  • Which economists have influenced you the most?
You’ll have to click to the interview for answers!

Thanks to Aaron Steelman, Lisa Kenney and especially  Renee Haltom, who helped a lot with the editing. I’m a lot less coherent in person!
Making fun of people's names?

Making fun of people's names?

Paul Krugman is now reduced to making fun of my name.

I was alerted to the fact that we were living in a Dark Age of macroeconomics when the same cockroach put in an appearance at the University of Chicago.
Oh how clever. I haven’t heard that one since about, hmm, first grade, circa 1965. (Follow the link if you’re not sure who he’s talking about.)

Paul continues
Now, some people get all upset by this terminology. Why can’t I be serious and respectful? Well, the answer is that we’re not having a serious conversation
No, the royal “we” are not.

I suppose I should read this as a welcome sign of desperation; that Krugman, having run out of ideas, and unwilling to read the interesting “serious conversation” regarding stimulus that the rest of us are having in the academic literature (say, my own recent modest contribution), is reduced to endlessly flogging the old “Say’s law” calumny and now this.

Here are Krugman’s similarly profound thoughts about Narayana Kocherlakota’s name.
Healthcare tidbits

Healthcare tidbits

Tidbits that came in following my WSJ oped last week

1. I heard from a lot of people in the burgeoning market for cash only transparent service. Maybe the internet will undercut the current non-competitive system! Some nice links:

http://selfpaypatient.com/ A blog devoted to self-pay patients and doctors.The first post is cool – why passing laws to force price transparency won’t work.

http://www.amazon.com/The-Self-Pay-Patient-Affordable-Healthcare-ebook/dp/B00HBUPLFG/ The e book. Haven’t read, looks interesting.

http://surgerycenterofoklahoma.tumblr.com/ Dr. Keith Smith, of Surgery Center of Oklahoma, who I wrote about last week, has a nice tumblr.

 www.regencyhealthnyc.com.  An interesting direct cash pay pricing surgical clinic

2. The “last embassy” blog points out a curious feature of Obamacare: you need a credit card or bank account – plus internet connection – to sign up. That’s a bit of a problem for poor uninsured people supposedly the beneficiaries of this system. I do sense a bit of a disconnect between the people who designed Obamacare, and the intended beneficiaries – who don’t have a computer, high speed broadband, strong internet skills, credit card and bank account, and who shop (like all of us) by word of mouth. (“They have no computers? Let them use their ipads” a modern Marie Antoinette might say)
http://thelastembassy.blogspot.com/2013/05/the-aca-and-unbankable-or-steve-miller_22.html

3. Cato’s Michael Cannon produced an extraordinary comprehensive listing of Adminstration executive orders on Obamacare. I salute Michael’s patience to slog through this. Get to the excellent last two paragraphs.
http://www.forbes.com/sites/michaelcannon/2013/12/27/as-predicted-obamacare-plunges-into-utter-chaos/

4. Media. I did a few interviews following the WSJ oped

Fox
http://video.foxbusiness.com/v/2976885479001/the-steps-to-fixing-obamacare/

CNBC’s Kudlow report
http://video.cnbc.com/gallery/?play=1&video=3000231610

Not very enlightening, really.

5. Hilarious tidbit. I know, it’s hard to clean up websites.

http://www.whitehouse.gov/realitycheck/3



What to do when Obamacare unravels

What to do when Obamacare unravels

Wall Street Journal Oped December 26 2013.

The unraveling of the Affordable Care Act presents a historic opportunity for change. Its proponents call it “settled law,” but as Prohibition taught us, not even a constitutional amendment is settled law—if it is dysfunctional enough, and if Americans can see a clear alternative.

Source: David Gothard, Wall Street Journal
This fall’s website fiasco and policy cancellations are only the beginning. Next spring the individual mandate is likely to unravel when we see how sick the people are who signed up on exchanges, and if our government really is going to penalize voters for not buying health insurance. The employer mandate and “accountable care organizations” will take their turns in the news. There will be scandals. There will be fraud. This will go on for years.

Yet opponents should not sit back and revel in dysfunction. The Affordable Care Act was enacted in response to genuine problems. Without a clear alternative, we will simply patch more, subsidize more, and ignore frauds and scandals, as we do in Medicare and other programs.

There is an alternative. A much freer market in health care and health insurance can work, can deliver high quality, technically innovative care at much lower cost, and solve the pathologies of the pre-existing system.

The U.S. health-care market is dysfunctional. Obscure prices and $500 Band-Aids are legendary. The reason is simple: Health care and health insurance are strongly protected from competition. There are explicit barriers to entry, for example the laws in many states that require a “certificate of need” before one can build a new hospital. Regulatory compliance costs, approvals, nonprofit status, restrictions on foreign doctors and nurses, limits on medical residencies, and many more barriers keep prices up and competitors out. Hospitals whose main clients are uncompetitive insurers and the government cannot innovate and provide efficient cash service.

We need to permit the Southwest Airlines, Wal-Mart, Amazon.com and Apples of the world to bring to health care the same dramatic improvements in price, quality, variety, technology and efficiency that they brought to air travel, retail and electronics. We’ll know we are there when prices are on hospital websites, cash customers get discounts, and new hospitals and insurers swamp your inbox with attractive offers and great service.

The Affordable Care Act bets instead that more regulation, price controls, effectiveness panels, and “accountable care” organizations will force efficiency, innovation, quality and service from the top down. Has this ever worked? Did we get smartphones by government pressure on the 1960s AT&T phone monopoly? Did effectiveness panels force United Airlines and American Airlines to cut costs, and push TWA and Pan Am out of business? Did the post office invent FedEx, UPS and email? How about public schools or the last 20 or more health-care “cost control” ideas?

Only deregulation can unleash competition. And only disruptive competition, where new businesses drive out old ones, will bring efficiency, lower costs and innovation.

Health insurance should be individual, portable across jobs, states and providers; lifelong and guaranteed-renewable, meaning you have the right to continue with no unexpected increase in premiums if you get sick. Insurance should protect wealth against large, unforeseen, necessary expenses, rather than be a wildly inefficient payment plan for routine expenses.

People want to buy this insurance, and companies want to sell it. It would be far cheaper, and would solve the pre-existing conditions problem. We do not have such health insurance only because it was regulated out of existence. Businesses cannot establish or contribute to portable individual policies, or employees would have to pay taxes. So businesses only offer group plans. Knowing they will abandon individual insurance when they get a job, and without cross-state portability, there is little reason for young people to invest in lifelong, portable health insurance. Mandated coverage, pressure against full risk rating, and a dysfunctional cash market did the rest.

Rather than a mandate for employer-based groups, we should transition to fully individual-based health insurance. Allow national individual insurance offered and sold to anyone, anywhere, without the tangled mess of state mandates and regulations. Allow employers to contribute to individual insurance at least on an even basis with group plans. Current group plans can convert to individual plans, at once or as people leave. Since all members in a group convert, there is no adverse selection of sicker people.

ObamaCare defenders say we must suffer the dysfunction and patch the law, because there is no alternative. They are wrong. On Nov. 2, for example, New York Times NYT columnist Nicholas Kristof wrote movingly about his friend who lost employer-based insurance and died of colon cancer. Mr. Kristof concluded, “This is why we need Obamacare.” No, this is why we need individual, portable, guaranteed-renewable, inexpensive, catastrophic-coverage insurance.

On Nov. 15, MIT’s Jonathan Gruber, an ObamaCare architect, argued on Realclearpolitics that “we currently have a highly discriminatory system where if you’re sick, if you’ve been sick or you’re going to get sick, you cannot get health insurance.” We do. He concluded that the Affordable Care Act is “the only way to end that discriminatory system.” It is not.

On Dec. 3, President Obama himself said that “the only alternative that Obamacare’s critics have, is, well, let’s just go back to the status quo.” Not so.

What about the homeless guy who has a heart attack? Yes, there must be private and government-provided charity care for the very poor. What if people don’t get enough checkups? Send them vouchers. To solve these problems we do not need a federal takeover of health care and insurance for you, me, and every American.

No other country has a free health market, you may object. The rest of the world is closer to single payer, and spends less.

Sure. We can have a single government-run airline too. We can ban FedEx and UPS, and have a single-payer post office. We can have government-run telephones and TV. Thirty years ago every other country had all of these, and worthies said that markets couldn’t work for travel, package delivery, the “natural monopoly” of telephones and TV. Until we tried it. That the rest of the world spends less just shows how dysfunctional our current system is, not how a free market would work.

While economically straightforward, liberalization is always politically hard. Innovation and cost reduction require new businesses to displace familiar, well-connected incumbents. Protected businesses spawn “good jobs” for protected workers, dues for their unions, easy lives for their managers, political support for their regulators and politicians, and cushy jobs for health-policy wonks. Protection from competition allows private insurance to cross-subsidize Medicare, Medicaid, and emergency rooms.

But it can happen. The first step is, the American public must understand that there is an alternative. Stand up and demand it.

Comments

Thanks as usual to my superb editor at the WSJ, Howard Dickman.

This is the Oped version of my essay, After the ACA; go there for more details. In case I have to hit you over the head with the point, we need to focus on the supply of health care as well as health insurance. For guaranteed renewable insurance and solving preexisting conditions read “Health Status Insurance” etc. here.

The comments on Hope for Healthcare and some followup correspondence paint an intriguing picture. Take a look at goodrx.comwww.oration.com and also at the health technology review in last Saturday’s WSJ, “5 high tech fixes.” The internet undermined un-competitive behavior and non-transparent prices in cars, electronics, life insurance, and many other fields. Maybe, just maybe, it can undermine the hospital-insurer-government complex too. I ran out of space to write about that, but there is hope.

I was thinking a little bit about the exchanges and the latest latest deadline chaos, and the following occurred to me: They are restructuring an entire market, basically substituting website exchanges for insurance brokers and company marketing. They are redefining an entire product space–individual health insurance. And then announcing that an entire country has to sign up in about a month.

Think how any other new product or marketplace is introduced, especially a complex one like health insurance. There is a whole spread of word of mouth, magazine and internet reviews, company marketing efforts, friends and relatives pass on what they learned, which plans are good, which are bad, which networks have good doctors in your area, and so on.  They ignored this entire new-product process. And then wonder that it’s not working so great.

Well I guess it’s appropriate for the season. Augustus Obama decreed that each must be registered with healthcare.gov. So Joseph and Mary, lacking a computer, went to a public library to register. But she was with child, and the website crashed while Joseph was entering their income history, so there among the books a child was born…


Why English Majors (and their editors) Should Take an Economics Class

Why English Majors (and their editors) Should Take an Economics Class

To avoid writing silly articles, as appeared in the Sunday New York Times under the title “Triumph of the English Major.” Gerald Howard, a book editor in New York City writes of an early experience:

I had the idea that we should reissue two early novels by the fine writer Alice Adams…

So there I was in our C.F.O.’s office with a P. & L. that just eked out a 7 percent return. He looked at that piece of paper dubiously….Then, with that wry and sad expression with which financial people have regarded liberal arts people since at least the invention of movable type and perhaps even written language, he signed off on my shortfallen P. & L. and said to me, “You know, we could make more money by just putting this advance into a certificate of deposit.”

I knew he was right…C.D.’s were paying 10 percent per annum or more….

However, as I went back to my office I experienced an instance of what the French call “stair wit.” I thought, wait a minute, I am putting that $7,500 to work. It’s an investment. The chain of activity I am putting in motion will give work to printers and shippers. It will provide bookstores (there were still bookstores) with tangible goods to sell at a profit. The revenue from those sales will help to pay my salary, my colleagues’ salaries, even our C.F.O.’s salary. Alice Adams will have some thousands of dollars in her pocket — maybe to invest in a C.D. All this and a few thousand people fewer than I put down on the P. & L. (I’d lied, of course) will have bought and enjoyed two excellent novels that deserved to be in print.

Whereas if we’d just put that money in the hands of a bank, they would just … well, I was pretty hazy on what a bank would actually do with that money, but my general sense was that it would sit there in a vault microbially propagating itself and what good would that do anybody? Economically I was putting my shoulder — or Penguin’s shoulder — to the wheel! I came away with the conviction that I wasn’t useless anymore.
This makes a good quiz question for an undergraduate micro class. Make it an essay question, for the English majors. “What’s wrong with this story?”


There is a reason for that “wry and sad” expression. The French may call it “stair wit.” Or perhaps that was “bêtises d'escalier?” Maybe “fall down the stairs wit?”

Because of course money in the hands of a bank does not “microbially propagate” itself in a way that does no good to anybody. Perhaps I can appeal to literary sensibility with a few song lyrics, explaining what will happen to young Michael Banks’ tuppence invested wisely in the bank:
You see, Michael, you’ll be part of
Railways through Africa
Dams across the Nile
Fleets of ocean greyhounds
Majestic, self-amortizing canals
Plantations of ripening tea
(Ok, the song goes on to “think of the foreclosures..” but we don’t want to get in that here.)

The $7,500 dollars Mr. Howard invested in a book would have been lent out by the bank to someone else, who would have invested it in a better project. Someone might have started a restaurant, or even a bookstore. Every single dollar of goods, every single job created by his investment, would have been created by the alternative, and more.

He just didn’t see the (say) new immigrant, turned down on a loan application for $7,500 to start that lifetime dream restaurant. Or turned down on a mortgage application, thus denying a whole construction crew a summer’s employment. And the lumberyard its sales and so on. The invisible hand is, alas, invisible.

That is a great strength of the market. It works, even when the people involved don’t understand it. Alas, democracy requires voters with some clue.

Oh. And who is this boss who signs off on obviously cooked 7% return projects when CDs were yielding 10? No wonder print media is going down the toilet. And who are the editors who signed off on this piece? I don’t write for the Times (I try on occasion, but they always reject me). But at the Wall Street Journal, they tear apart my prose and push every little detail of fact and logic. Do the NYT editors not know that banks do not microbially propagate money?

Mr Howard concludes
…future epochs will remember us as a coarse and philistine people who squandered our bottomlessly rich cultural inheritance for short-term and meaningless financial advantage.
And that is why you should major in English.
I think it more likely that future epochs, if there are any after we screw this one up, will remember us as a pampered people who squandered our bottomlessly rich scientific and financial heritage by willful ignorance of how it works.

Majoring in English is a fine thing to do. We need more good writers.  But take an economics class, so when you write about the world, your elegant prose does not reflect complete ignorance about how that world works. You don’t need to suffer equations. Reading Smith, Hayek, and Friedman will do.

Bah Humbug!
Hope for healthcare?

Hope for healthcare?

Can this Man Save Health care?” is another nice article about Dr. Keith Smith, founder of the Surgery Center of Oklahoma (SCO) in Oklahoma City. (Previous blog post here.)  He is trying the audacious, running a low-price hospital with prices posted on the web – the Southwest Airlines of hospitals that I’ve been hoping for.

Smith knew that putting his prices online had been a great idea when Canadians began flying down to the SCO for treatment…
In addition to targeting the uninsured and Canadians, Smith has also had success in appealing to people with high deductibles…
Smith’s transparent pricing has already had a significant impact on the healthcare market in Oklahoma City. Smith says, “What we’ve done by putting these prices online is created a price war, and it’s really going on in Oklahoma City.” With the SCO as an option for residents, the big nonprofit hospitals in the city are having difficulty continuing to charge their inflated rates. “The big hospitals,” Smith says, “have been thrust into a market economy whether they like it or not.” Consumers finally have the option to shop around for the best medical care. 
The effects have been felt throughout the region. The Oklahoma Heart Hospital and the nearby McBride Orthopedic Hospital have both followed the SCO’s lead in publishing their prices in an effort to attract consumers. Worried that they were losing heart patients to the Oklahoma Heart Hospital, Galichia Heart Hospital in nearby Wichita has also published its rates, creating the first semblance of the price war Smith has been trying to start.
He believes that his model can cut into the profits of big healthcare: “The big hospital’s nightmare has arrived.”  
This is an interesting observation. The established hospitals, working with the established insurers were not competing with each other. It took an upstart with a new business model to provoke competition. It is ever thus, but this is not the model our regulators use when they think of competition.

Another interesting observation. The existing insurers were not at all anxious to save money through him. He had to go around them to cash customers, Canadians, and directly to companies.
Smith has also had success in appealing to people with high deductibles and to mid-sized companies in Oklahoma and North Texas.
He has directly courted companies that feel that they are overpaying for their HMOs…
Smith admits that his strategy hasn’t won him any friends in the healthcare establishment or, as he refers to it, the healthcare cartel: “I don’t get invited to any big hospital garden parties.” In fact, he claims that “giant hospital chains and insurance companies were lined up arm-in-arm” to prevent the SCO from succeeding. Following its opening, business suffered for several years because it was locked out of insurance plans that would rather pay the higher in-network amounts at the bigger hospitals across town. The SCO only became profitable when it went over insurers’ heads and pursued corporate clients directly. “The big hospitals and insurance companies hurt us for a while,” Smith says, “but we stayed with it; now they’re sucking wind. 
Sometimes people say I am foaming at the mouth too much when I refer to our current system as crony-capitalist, captured-regulator and so on, and getting worse. Perhaps I’m not exaggerating after all.

There is a ray of hope. The large deductibles  on many exchange policies leave people some incentive to shop. Not as much as you’d think – there still is the in network and out of network business, and once you hit the deductible the sky is the limit. But some. Can a mass of patients who care about money stimulate a competitive supply market?
The big question on my mind, is, will our government allow this ray of hope to emerge?  As Smith found out, there are powerful forces in the local hospitals and large insurers that want to stop him. Now they have a powerful friend in the ACA.

Will the employer mandate allow companies to go around big insurers in this way? Or will they be forced to participate in cross-subsidies through the established insurers? Will these side deals be deemed “ACA-Compliant” employer-provided insurance? Will ACA-approved high-deductible plans be allowed to use him? Will he be allowed to give cash customers a discount? He so undermines the whole structure I can’t see how they can let it happen.
Smith hopes, however, that he and a handful of other transparent fee-for-service providers will be the vanguard of a free-market movement that runs parallel to the ACA.
That would be wonderful. A free-market system could emerge alongside the ACA, and then people like me will not have to prove that there is indeed a promised land on the other side of the waters, the promised land will appear on its own.

If the ACA will allow it. Competition undermines cross-subsidies, and competition undercuts powerful lobbies to a very powerful regulator.
Williamson on the economics blogosphere

Williamson on the economics blogosphere

Steve Williamson has an insightful set of posts, Minneapolis Redux, and Journalists Looking for a Fight. They are tangentially on the Minneapolis Fed affair, but really about the coverage of the affair and deeply thoughtful about how the economics blogosphere is evolving.

Reporters at the Minneapolis Star-Tribune, the Financial Times, the Wall Street Journal, and other outlets were fair, I think. They talked to the people involved, and covered the story the way good reporters should. What went on in the economics blogosphere I think is revealing of what this medium can and cannot do. In many cases, bloggers dived into the story and did what they do best. They made stuff up, or repeated things that have become “blog truths” - basically fiction that, when repeated often enough, somehow becomes truthy. 
So, this runs from the outrageous to the comical, covering all points in between….
His own posts here set a high standard for looking up, checking, and linking to the things he’s talking about. Hopefully the market test will induce us all to better blogging.

What if we got the sign wrong on monetary policy?

I’ve been following with interest the rumblings of economists playing with an amazing idea – what if we have the sign wrong on monetary policy? Could it be that raising the interest rate raises inflation, and not the other way around?

Most recently, Steve Williamson plays with this idea towards the end of a recent provocative blog post.   Most of Steve’s post is about the Phillips curve, but he concludes

If the Fed actually wants to increase the inflation rate over the medium term, the short-term nominal interest rate has to go up.

So, here’s the policy advice for our friends on the FOMC…If there’s any tendency for inflation to change over time, it’s in a negative direction, as long as the Fed keeps the interest rate on reserves at 0.25%. Forget about forward guidance…So, as long as the interest rate on reserves stays at 0.25%…you’re losing by falling short of the 2% inflation target, which apparently you think is important. And you’ll keep losing. So, what you should do is Volcker in reverse.. For good measure, do one short, large QE intervention. Then, either simultaneously or shortly after, increase the policy rate. Under current conditions, the overnight nominal rate does not have to go up much to get 2% inflation over the medium term.
Conventional wisdom says no, of course: raising interest rates lowers inflation in the short run and and only raises inflation in a very long run if at all.

The data don’t scream such a negative relation. Both the secular trend and the business cycle pattern show a decent positive association of interest rates with inflation, culminating in our current period of inflation slowly drifting down despite the Fed’s $3 trillion dollars worth of QE.



To be sure, I left the grand Volcker stabilization out of the picture here, where a sharp spike in interest rates preceded the sudden end of inflation. And to be sure, there is a standard story to explain negative causation with positive correlation. But there are other stories too – the US embarked on a joint fiscal-monetary stabilization in 1982, then under the shadow of an implicit inflation target gradually lowered inflation and interest rates. Other countries that adopted explicit inflation targets have similar-looking data.  And every time George Washington got sicker, his doctors drained more blood.

So much for data, how about theory? Why do we think that higher interest rates produce lower inflation? We are now, in fact, in a new environment, and old theories may not apply any more.

The first standard story was money. In the past, when the Fed wanted to raise rates, it sold bonds, cutting down on the $50 billion of non-interest-paying reserves. The standard story was, with less “money” in the economy and somewhat sticky prices, nominal interest rates would rise temporarily.  The less money would eventually mean less inflation, and then and only then would nominal rates decline. In this  view, running the Fed was a tricky job, like driving 68 Volkswagen bus in a crosswind, since the steering was connected to the wheels in the wrong direction in the short run.

However, we are likely to stay with huge excess reserves and interest on reserves. When the Fed wants to raise interest rates now, it will simply pay more on reserves and bingo, interest rates rise. We will remain as awash in interest-paying reserves as before. So this 1960s monetary mechanism just won’t apply. Is it possible that in the interest-on-reserves world, raising interest rates translates right away into larger inflation?

More recent economic thinking has (rightly, I think) left the money vs. bonds distinction in the dust. The “Paleo-Keyneisian” (credit to Paul Krugman for inventing this nice word) models in policy circles state that the Fed raises rates, this lowers “demand,” and through the Phillips curve, lower demand means less inflation. No money in sight here, but yes a negative effect. The first half of Steve’s blog post tearing apart the Phillips curve at least should question one’s utter confidence in that mechanism.

Paleo-Keynesian models aren’t really economics though. What do new-Keynesian (DSGE)  models say? Interestingly, new-Keynesian models can quite easily produce a positive effect of interest rates on inflation. Here are two examples (The models I use here are discussed in more depth in “Determinacy and Identification with Taylor Rules” and “The New-Keynesian Liquidity Trap”)

Lets’ start with the absolutely simplest New-Keynesian model, a Fisher equation and a Taylor rule,
\[ i_t = E_t \pi_{t+1} \] \[ i_t = \phi_{\pi} \pi_t + v_t \]
The standard solution ( \(\phi_{\pi} \gt 1 \) and choosing the nonexplosive equilibrium) is
\[ \pi_t = -E_t \sum_{j=0}^{\infty} \phi^{-(j+1)} v_{t+j}. \]
So, suppose \(v_t\)=0 for \(t \lt T\) and imagine an unexpected permanent tightening to \(v_t=v \) for \(t \ge T\). Interest rates and inflation are zero (deviations from trend) until T, and then

\[ \pi_t =i_t = -\frac{1}{\phi_{\pi}-1} v \]
Both inflation and the interest rate jump down together. Wait, you say, I thought this was a tightening, why are interest rates going down? It is a tightening – v is positive. The Fed deviates from its Taylor rule, so interest rates are higher than they would be for this inflation rate. But an observer sees interest rates and inflation move together, both going down. Conversely, if the Fed were to “loosen” by deviating from its Taylor rule in a lower direction, then we would see inflation and interest rates move immediately and positively together. I’m not sure news papers would call this “tighter interest rates!”

A better way to think of this experiment is, what if the Fed adopted a higher inflation target? Rewrite the Taylor rule as
\[ i_t = \phi_{\pi} \left(\pi_t -\pi^*_t \right) \]
You see this is the same, with \(v_t = -\phi_{\pi}\pi^*_t \). So, if the Fed suddenly (and credibly!) raises its inflation target from \(\pi^*_t=0\) to \(\pi^*_t=\pi^* \gt 0 \) at \(t=T\), inflation and interest rates jump from zero to
\[ \pi_t =i_t = \frac{\phi_{\pi}}{\phi_{\pi}-1}\pi^*. \]
The higher inflation target gives instantly higher inflation – and must come with a sudden rise in the Fed’s interest rate target!

Blog readers will know I’m not much of a fan of the standard New-Keynesian equilibrium selection devices. But since this “model” is only an Fisher equation, obviously it’s going to be even easier to see a positive connection between interest rates and inflation in other equilibria of this model. For example, take \(\phi_{\pi}=0\) (as we must at the zero bound anyway) and choose the equilibrium that has zero fiscal effects, i.e. no unexpected inflation at time T.
\[ i_t = E_t \pi_{t+1} \] \[ i_t = v_t \] Now, a sudden unexpected rise from \(i_t=0\) to \(i_t=v\) for \(t \ge T\) gives us \(\pi_T\)=0 (no unexpected inflation) but then \(\pi_t=v\) for \(t=T+1,T+2,….\). In words, the Fed raises rates at \(T\), there is a one-period pause and then inflation rises to match the higher interest rate after this one-period pause. 

“But what about price-stickiness?” I hear you protesting, and rightly. The whole story about a temporary effect in the wrong direction hinges on price stickiness and Phillips curves. I happen to have a paper and program handy with explicit solutions so let’s look. The model is the standard continuous time New-Keynesian model, 
\[ \frac{dx_{t}}{dt} =i_{t}-\pi _{t} \] \[ \frac{d\pi _{t}}{dt} =\rho \pi _{t}-\kappa x_{t}. \]
Now, suppose the Fed raises the interest rate from zero to a constant i starting at time T. This is a simple matrix differential equation with solution
 \begin{equation*} \left[ \begin{array}{c} \kappa x_{t} \ \pi _{t} \end{array} \right] =\left[ \begin{array}{c} \rho \ 1 \end{array} \right] i+\left[ \begin{array}{c} \lambda ^{p} \ 1 \end{array} \right] e^{\lambda ^{m}\left( t-T\right) }z_{T} \end{equation*}
where
\begin{eqnarray*} \lambda ^{p} &=&\frac{1}{2}\left( \rho +\sqrt{\rho ^{2}+4\kappa }\right) \geq 0 \ \lambda ^{m} &=&\frac{1}{2}\left( \rho -\sqrt{\rho ^{2}+4\kappa }\right) \leq 0. \end{eqnarray*}
There are multiple solutions, as usual, indexed by \(z_T\), equivalently by what inflation does at time T. The inflation target or Taylor rule selects these, but rather than get in to that, let’s just look at the possibilities:


Here I graphed an interest rate rise from 0 to 5% (blue dash)  and the possible equilibrium values for inflation (red). (I used \(\kappa=1\, \ \rho=1\) ).

As you can see, it’s perfectly possible, despite the price-stickiness of the new-Keynesian Phillips curve, to see the super-neutral result, inflation rises instantly. The equilibrium I liked in “New-Keynesian Liquidity Trap” with no instantaneous response produces a gradual rise in inflation. The only way to get a big decline in inflation is to imagine that by a second “equilibrium selection policy” the Fed insists on a quick jump down in inflation.

Obviously this is not the last word. But, it’s interesting how easy it is to get positive inflation out of an interest rate rise in this simple new-Keynesian model with price stickiness.

So, to sum up, the world is different. Lessons learned in the past do not necessarily apply to the interest on ample excess reserves world to which we are (I hope!) headed. The mechanisms that prescribe a negative response of inflation to interest rate increases are a lot more tenuous than you might have thought. Given the downward drift in inflation, it’s an idea that’s worth playing with.

I don’t “believe” it yet (I hate that word – there are models and evidence, not “beliefs” – but this is the web, and it’s easy for the fire-breathing bloggers of the left to jump on this sort of playfulness and write “my God, that moron Cochrane ‘believes’ monetary policy signs are wrong” – so one has to clarify this sort of thing.) We need to explore the question in a much wider variety of models. But it is certainly a fascinating question. What is the connection between interest rates and inflation in the interest-on reserves world? If one wants to raise inflation, is Steve right that raising rates does the trick?

By the way, none of this is an endorsement of the idea that more inflation is a good thing. If interest rates stay low, and we trend to zero inflation or even slight deflation, why wouldn’t we just welcome the Friedman rule – inflation  policy has attained perfection, on to other things? Technically, welfare calculations come after understanding policy in these models, and “believing” that all our seemingly endless doldrums can all be fixed with a little monetary magic like taxing reserves is another proposition that needs a lot more support.  More likely, if you don’t like the long-term economy, go fix “supply” and growth where the problems are.  Nobody’s Phillips curve gives a big output gap with steady inflation.

History: I last thought about this question here, in response to a John Taylor Op-Ed also suggesting that raising rates might be stimulative. This sign is an old question. The last time it came up was around the stabilization of 1980-1982. A school suggested money was “superneutral.” They were wrong, I think, in the short run, at the time. I wrote my thesis showing there is a short run effect of money on interest rates, in the expected direction, which tells you a bit about how long monetary controversies go on. But both interest rates and unemployment did come down much faster than the Paleo-Keynesians of the time thought possible.  It’s definitely time to rethink it.

There is lots more good stuff in Steve’s post. Like causality and Japan:
.. There used to be a worry (maybe still is) of “turning into Japan.” I think what people meant when they said that, is that low inflation, or deflation, was a causal factor in Japan’s poor average economic performance over the last 20 years. In fact, I think that “turning into Japan” means getting into a state where the central bank sees poor real economic performance as something it can cure with low nominal interest rates. Low nominal interest rates ultimately produce low inflation, and as long as economic stagnation persists (for reasons that have nothing to do with monetary policy), the central bank persists in keeping nominal interest rates low, and inflation continues to be low. Thus, we associate stagnation with low inflation, or deflation.
and the value of forward guidance without commitment
You’ve [Fed] pretty much blown that, by moving from “extended period” language, to calendar dates, to thresholds, and then effectively back to extended periods. That’s cheap talk, and everyone sees it that way
And the whole Phillips curve thing is good stuff too.  But we’re here to talk about the possible negative sign.

(Thanks to Frank Diebold for showing me how to get MathJax to work in blogger. )

Three Nobel Lectures, and the Rhetoric of Finance



It was my great pleasure – and honor – to attend this year’s Nobel prize ceremonies. It started with the Nobel prize lectures, which I found very thought provoking.

Shiller 

I’ll work backwards, as it was thinking about Bob Shiller’s talk that taught me the biggest lesson. Preview: this will start pretty negative, but I learn a big lesson by the end. Hang in there, Shiller fans.

I thought I thought we had reached a consensus on volatility tests. Shiller (and others) brought us volatility tests, while Fama (and others), starting in 1975, showed that all sorts of returns are forecastable at long horizon. After sturm und drang, we – including Campbell and Shiller, but also a wider literature (I wrote a few papers) – realized that volatility tests are exactly, mathematically equivalent to return forecasting regressions. Expected returns (true measure) vary over time, a lot, and fully account for volatility tests.

The remaining question is whether time-varying expected returns are connected to macroeconomic quantities through marginal rates of transformation and substitution, or whether people misperceive probabilities and don’t know about time-varying expected returns.

There is a joint hypothesis theorem – probability and marginal utility always enter together in asset pricing formulas – so no amount of staring at prices will ever solve this interpretation question. We need models.  Economic models (such as habit persistence) give a somewhat successful answer, but are also rejected. The great challenge for behavioral finance is to produce similar, scientific - looking models that tie irrational expectations to other data in a rejectable way, and thus rise above ex-post story telling.

Volatility tests were a deeply important, Nobel-worthy part of this story. They showed the economic importance of time-varying expected returns – and the as yet incomplete effort to understand those returns – in a way that t stats and R2 values did not.

Well, that’s what I thought the consensus was. What I found remarkable is just how much of that consensus Bob completely abjured.

At 1:12 Bob starts right in:

What is a bubble? You [Gene Fama] said nobody defines it. So I will define it. A speculative bubble is a fad. People get excited sometimes. Too excited… Prices start going up, they start talking, the newspapers start writing about it, more and more people pile in to a market and they push prices up more and it goes on for a while. eventually it breaks and the bubble bursts.
That’s not a “definition.” That’s an explanation, a theory. A definition tells you in an operational way what pattern in the data describes “bubble.” An explanation is a theory that predicts the defined phenomenon.

That doesn’t answer Gene at all. Gene asked Bob how to measure a price above “fundamentals.” how to measure that a “fad” is underway? For example, in a previous podcast, Gene had offered to believe in bubbles if Bob could show a method that reliably forecast a negative market expected return.

Bob pointedly did not take even that olive branch, that chance to agree on a common language.  If we can’t get straight what a definition is vs. an explanation, maybe the physicists are right that they shouldn’t give out economics Nobels. We’ll surely be at this another 35 years.

Next, Bob put up an update of the famous volatility graph, where he contrasts actual prices with ex-post dividends discounted at a constant rate. (1:15:45)



He called the dividend line “the actual market if everyone knew the future” and the “true value.”

(A minor thought. Really? Would the world really be working right if that’s what stock prices had all the return and no risk? If we have an equity premium puzzle now, imagine what it would look like with no risk! If prices have no risk so we should discount dividends with riskfree rates, the major failure of today’s markets is not the volatility of the price-dividend ratio, it’s the level, which should be many times higher?)

Admitting briefly that efficient markets allow some return forecastability, he showed us some graphs discounting dividends with interest rates and consumption growth raised to a power.

On this evidence,  he concluded that we are  "seeing repeated fads and fashions" though they are “integrated with the economy” in a  way that is “difficult to understand.” Nonetheless, we can conclude that “The market is too volatile, people are a little crazy, there is a social psychological component.”

How do we we get from the failure of one model (constant expected returns, or power utility) to the failure of any possible model, to “people are a little crazy?”

More deeply, in the face of the joint hypothesis theorem, how do you get to claim victory for any view without a model at all?

More deeply, we’ve all been over and over this.  The subsequent literature answered all this years ago. How could Bob not know that or even mention it?

At 1:23, he described the Campbell-Ammer variance decomposition, concluding “only about a half or a third of the fluctuations in the stock market could be explained by evidence about future dividends,” and concluding, “so most of the market doesn’t make sense”



This was really revealing. Bob’s Campbell-Ammer slide says “excess [expected] return variation two to three times that of [expected] dividend innovation” His words were “most of the market doesn’t make sense!”

Add this up and it’s all eye-popping. Bob is basically denying the 20 year old theorem that volatility tests are equivalent to time-varying expected returns. I listened to the lecture and carefully to the video. You won’t find an admission of that theorem, or that mechanically time varying expected returns account for these plots. That’s especially astonishing given that the Nobel committee cited him for discovering long-run return forecastability, ignoring Fama’s role! For example the Nobel poster said
“Beginning in the 1960s Eugne Fama demonstrated that stock prices are extremely difficult to predict in the short run. .. If Fama’s results are right, then shouldn’t it be even harder to make predictions over several years? The answer is no, as Robert Shiller discovered in the early 1980s.”
Bob is denying the joint-hypothesis theorem that probability and marginal utility always enter together, so we need a model of either to say anything. And Bob is denying the essence of what it means to supply a definition.    

Bob closed with an overview of psychology and sociology concepts that inspire his views,

He urged economists to incorporate more ideas from psychology, sociology and other fields, “I think that in understanding speculative bubbles we have to be eclectic. .. population biology… epidemiology, neuro economics.. To understand complex phenomenal we need to take account of every kind of expertise.”

OK,  "listen to psychologists" is good advice. Economics has benefitted from intellectual arbitrage many times in the past. But Nobel prizes are supposed to be given for past successes (typically, long-past!) not “maybe you can do something with this in the future.”

In an entire lecture, Bob did not give a single concrete example of how “listening to psychologists” produces one concrete positive step to understanding “bubbles.”

(There was a lot more in Bob’s speech, including description of his innovative work with Case in  constructing a real estate price index. Curiously, he showed how today’s forward prices are forecasting another “bubble” – this market price correctly forecasts “fundamentals,” unlike all the others? And he closed,  advocating more markets, such as GDP futures, admitting they will have bubbles and fads too, but that they are useful anyway. “What I’ve done is present imperfect evidence…with the conclusion that’s maybe radically different about bubbles, but not about the general importance of our financial markets.”)

Deep Breath. Another view

It slowly dawned on me though, that this is much too harsh an evaluation and an unsatisfactory theory. Bob is a smart and thoughtful guy.  The theory that he doesn’t know the difference between a definition and an explanation, hasn’t read Fama’s 1970 definition of “efficiency” or “joint hypothesis,” doesn’t understand that volatility is exactly the same as return forecastability, and so on, just doesn’t make sense. I remembered my Kuhn (Structure of Scientific Revolutions) and McCloskey (Rhetoric of Economics). (If you’re an economist and haven’t read these, do so now.)

I realized just how deep and audacious  Bob’s project is. He is telling us to abandon the “scientific” pretense. He wants us to adopt a literary style, where we look at the world, are inspired by psychology, and write interpretive prose as he has done.  When he says that the definition of a a bubble is a fad, he isn’t being sneaky and avoiding the argument. He means exactly what he says and wants us to think and write this way too. A bubble, to Bob, is defined as any time a time that he, writing about it, informed by psychology, and reading newspapers, thinks a “fad” is going on. And he invites us to think and write like that too. A model is, to Bob, wrapped up in one person’s judgement and not an objective machine. If I complain that this is ex-post story telling, he might say sure, stop pretending to be physics, write ex-post stories. If I complain that there are no rules and that this is no better than “the gods are angry,” he might say, no, read psychology not ancient theology, and the rules are you have to couch your story telling in their terms. He does not want us to try to construct models, either psychological or rational, that make quantitative predictions.

He wants to fundamentally remake how we do finance, how we talk about finance, how we write about finance. He wants to define a new rhetoric of finance. When he says we should read psychology and social psychology – and, implicitly, not physics or economics – he means exactly what he says. He (obviously) isn’t going to fall in the trap of writing rejectable models, making predictions and so forth. That’s like speaking Greek, and at his party, we speak Latin.

I am by nature a listener, an integrator. I wrote a paper on how volatility tests are the same as Fama French regressions. Bob has no interest at all in listening or integrating. He wants to redefine how we do things in his own style, as pure and simple as possible.

This is what scientific revolutions are all about. This is what Nobel Prizes are all about.  They give them to people who strike out, write a novel language and methodology for conducting research, and convince others to follow and do it their way and talk their language. All previous revolutions – successful or not – have had these interminable debates where we can’t even seem to agree on the meaning of simple words (“efficiency,” “definition”, “model”) and talk past each other. The salient facts and classic tests are only written ex post by the winners. Bob wants a revolution of that sort, and listening to economists is the last way to accomplish it.

Now that is an audacious project! And Bob has collected a lot of people who talk and write his way.  Not me, so far – only one in ten attempted scientific revolutions catch on, and I’m placing my bets elsewhere. I still like to talk like a physicist. But I think I understand the audacity of the project, and why it is we seem to talk to cross purposes and not even agree on basic questions like what constitutes a definition, what’s a theorem, and whether the absence of quantitative rejectable behavioral models that tie expected returns to other data matters or not. And why trying to debate – to ask for a definition of bubble, for a quantifiable measure of “fundamentals”, to ask for a quantiative model of distorted expectations – will get nowhere.

Hansen

With that thought in mind, I came to a similar different view of Lars Hansen’s talk. Lars isn’t in the middle of Gene and Bob;  Lars is way off on the other end of Bob.

Lars chose to talk more about his current research and less about the research that got him the prize, a good technique for these lectures. He’s working on “ambiguity,” how to handle the fact that we don’t really know what the right model is, and, even more interestingly, how to construct models in which the people in the models don’t really know what the right model is. Typically for Lars, this is a very deep research program, which may lead to a fundamental difference in how we think about risk and information in economics.

At one point he described which he described models with  "twisted expectations.“  Here’s the slide


In the first equation S with a tilde on it represents marginal utility, consumption to the gamma power in the usual formulation, X represents an asset payoff, and Q is then the price. This is the standard present value formula – except Lars wants to think about E as a "distorted” expectation. Following the usual theorems, in the bottom equation we can represent the same idea with the real expectation and an extra M term multiplying the stochastic discount factor. (Yes, everyone else uses M for Lars’ S, and P for his Q.) This is essentially the risk neutral valuation trick, that we can introduce a new “discount factor” M to represent the probability “twist.”

Seeing this, I would have been tempted to position it between Gene and Bob. Gene thinks of “efficiency” with true or rational expectations E. Bob thinks of inefficiency as “fads” meaning irrationally optimistic and pessimistic expectations. But Bob doesn’t show us how to link those irrational expectations to data. So I would have said this M, which Lars’ models do link to data, is a structured way to incorporate the non-rational distorted expectations that Bob thinks he sees into models, but in a disciplined, rejectable way.

Lars didn’t do that. In fact, when I suggested he position the talk as halfway between the “rational” and “behavioral” debate in this way, he said something deep, to the effect of he wished the whole rational-behavioral debate would just go away. Since it hasn’t gotten far in 35 years, he has a point.

But with Shiller behind me, I now understand Lars’ goal better. Lars, just like Bob, is setting forth a pure rhetoric, a pure language, a pure methodology for how we should think about finance and do finance. As Bob wants it to look like social psychology or maybe literary criticism, Lars wants it to look like physics. We write down the model, formally, and carefully. We test the model. We do not spend any time on loosely written ideas, either “rational” or “behavioral.” We don’t spend time on “alternative explanations” as is common in empirical finance.  We don’t pretend that empirical work can say anything useful about whole classes of models, like “economic” or “rational” or “psychological.” In Lars’ world, the whole rational-irrational debate is a waste of time. Show us your models, or be quiet. A test can tell you something about this model, period. At best a summary statistic like the Hansen-Jagannathan bound can tell you “this is what discount factors produced by any model must behave,” but that’s it.

This too is how Nobel Prizes are won. And looked at empirically – how many followers he has collected who write in his style – this is a successful language too.

Fama

Which brings me at last to Gene Fama, who came first. Gene gave a straightforward talk on efficient markets, long run forecastability  and empirical finance. The one slight zinger was putting down some equations and citations to remind the world that indeed he started documenting long-run return forecasts in 1975. He apparently had some behavioral finance zingers in reserve, but didn’t get time to give them. The written version will be interesting.

Looked at in this rhetorical light, Gene can afford to be gracious. Gene also invented a language, a methodology, for empirical fiance. And his language and methodology did not just attract a small band of followers, but took over the finance profession, so thoroughly and completely that it’s easy to forget his influence. When Gene runs Fama MacBeth regressions, we run Fama MacBeth regressions – even if GLS might be more efficient, even if time series variation might be informative. When Gene sorts stocks into 10 portfolios, we sort stocks into 10 portfolios – even if 20 or smooth kernels might make sense. When Gene uses monthly returns, we use monthly returns. Gene writes beautiful paragraphs of prose to describe his theories, (no criticism, it’s just comparative advantage) so do we. When Gene defines terms like “efficiency” and “joint hypothesis” the rest of us use those definitions.  When Gene points out differences between empirical finance and empirical economics, perhaps there you can see just how strong the Fama language effect has been.





Calomiris and Haber on the politics of bank regulation

Calomiris and Haber on the politics of bank regulation

Foreign Affairs has a very nice article “Why Banking Systems Succeed – And Fail: The Politics Behind Financial Institutions” by Charles Calomiris and Stephen Haber.

This is a healthy tonic for all us economists who seem to specialize in clever complex advice for the benevolent monarch sort of policy. It’s a good reminder of just how counterproductive our bank regulation is for economic ends, and how it serves well political ends.

They cover English vs. Scottish banking, US vs. Canada, and the roots of the dysfunctional US system that crashed in 2008. They are light on the current situation, but it isn’t hard to see the same groups feeding at the public trough before receiving tribute now.

Public choice often seems depressing, as if ideas don’t matter at all. But they do, and the last few paragraphs are thoughtful.

Within a democracy, effective reforms in banking require more than good ideas or brief windows of opportunity. What is crucial is persistent popular support for good ideas.
It does no good to assume that all the alternative feasible political bargains have already been considered and rejected.As George Bernard Shaw wrote, “The reasonable man adapts himself to the world: the unreasonable one persists in trying to adapt the world to himself. Therefore all progress depends on the unreasonable man.” Meaningful banking reform in a democracy depends on informed and stubborn unreasonableness.
“Informed and stubborn unreasonableness.” I like that a lot better than “tilting at windmills!”
Chris Demuth on Obamacare

Chris Demuth on Obamacare

Source: Weekly Standard
I found a nice Obamacare essay by Chris Demuth, “The Silence of the Liberals: Obamacare is Inimical to Their Values Too,” in the Weekly Standard.

The point: Liberals ought to join in the project of constructing a market-based alternative to Obamacare.  We do, in fact, have the same goals, and the question is simple cause-and-effect of what policies will actually produce those goals.

A few highlights with comments (but read the whole thing). We start with a quick reminder of the unfolding train wreck:
Obamacare will never achieve its promise of affordable health care for all paid for with improved efficiencies in health insurance and medical care. …the program improves “access” mainly by herding millions of people and firms into insurance they do not want or need. A great many will simply refuse, having little to fear for the time being, with the result that government expenditures will be far higher than projected. It is equally clear that the variety and quality of medical care will be seriously restricted for all concerned.
“Liberals” may not care about expenditures, but surely ought to worry on the last point.

The charge “you have no alternative” is false:
…many prominent Republicans and conservatives​…[and libertarians]…​have come forward with specific proposals for expanding affordable health care more than Obamacare does, while eliminating its many harmful and unworkable features. 
This is an important point. The alternatives will advance “liberal” values, and give people of modest means better care at lower cost than Obamacare. They “go further and aim higher.”  This is not the usual narrative of “people need” government help vs. stingy budget hawks. This is about a better way to achieve the same goals– and more.

What are we talking about? In a nutshell,
Tax and regulatory reforms, and targeted public subsidies, would provide portable and renewable insurance, including for those who have developed costly health conditions; would legalize (rather than banish) low-cost insurance for essential medical services..and would encourage direct purchase of routine medical goods and services where insurance has nothing to offer but paperwork
The hitch: this takes political courage.
Are Americans prepared to part with the illusion that everything related to “health” should be available free or far below cost…? Will they distinguish between higher-priced insurance for medical services they don’t need and insurance that leaves them to pay directly for services they do need but are quotidian and noncontingent? Do they understand that competition and innovation are as valuable in health care as in smartphones and coffee shops?
My emphasis, as this is the point I’ve been stressing most lately. Want cost control? Let the Southwest airlines and Walmart of health insurance enter and compete.
… The conservative reformers are betting that the public, now that it is paying attention, will answer in the affirmative. They may be right, but they need help.
The help we need is from “serious liberals,”
Serious liberals are those for whom the primary purpose of politics is to protect personal liberty and advance social equality.
I didn’t realize I was also a liberal!

Now, the two most important and novel reflections on Obamacare.  (Maybe this should come first!)
Obamacare’s two central features are as inimical to liberal values as to conservative values. The first is monopoly and the suppression of diversity and competition. The second is extreme concentration of power, exercised continuously in monitoring and directing the activities of millions of citizens.
Expanding on the first theme, which is on my mind but not common in health care discussions,
Obamacare … establishes a profusion of regulatory controls over prices, entry, and services in insurance and medical care, policies whose systematic anticonsumer perversities have been documented by generations of economists of all political persuasions…That some states operating their own Obamacare insurance “marketplaces” are already moving to ban the private sale of individual and small-business insurance is one example of the program’s tendency toward explicit monopoly.
More darkly, the second theme, also only beginning to get press:
But the most harrowing aspect of Obamacare is that it vests political executives and government administrators with sweeping discretionary power, free of conventional checks and balances. It gives federal officials the authority to set insurance prices without any of the economic and legal standards that govern regulation of public utilities…
Collaterally, Obamacare is introducing a new form of government​—​improvisational government, characterized by continuous ad hoc revisions of statutory law by executive decree. This is a reversion to a primitive form that long antedates our Constitution and rule-of-law traditions. Transported to the modern world, it leaves the private sector in a state of constant uncertainty and subjection.
And that’s only the beginning of the dangers of rule by executive decree with no checks and balances or legal recourse. (What large insurer will dare to stand up to the latest White House pronouncement?)

“Serious liberals,” libertarians and conservatives, can come together to fix this.
Serious liberals… should dare to join a coalition of reconstruction with the serious conservatives who have already dared to lay their cards on the table. There would be many significant disagreements to be hashed out… But the prospect of letting Obamacare run its course gives both sides a great deal to gain from compromise
Indeed.


Hansen Nobel Spanish Translation

Hansen Nobel Spanish Translation

Spanish translation of my blog post on Lars Hansen’s Nobel Prize

El premio Nobel de Lars Hansen (traducción al español de Pedro Cervera)

Lars ha realizado tal cantidad de investigación pionera y profunda, que ni siquiera puedo comenzar a enumerar la lista completa sin comentar que sólo entiendo una parte de ella.

Escribí capítulos enteros de mi libro de texto “Valoración de activos” basándome tan sólo en uno de los documentos de Hansen. Lars escribe para el futuro y normalmente tardamos diez años o más en entender lo que ha hecho y su verdadera importancia….

(para el resto, haga clic aquí (pdf))
Unintentionally hilarious Nobel coverage

Unintentionally hilarious Nobel coverage

Shawn Tully at Fortune wrote a very thoughtful piece describing Gene Fama’s research and views on efficient markets.

The version I saw on  CNN money magazine is unintentionally both hilarious, and ends up making a far deeper point than I think Shawn intended.  It is chock full of little links trying to draw you off to other articles on the magazine. These were undoubtedly not put in or even reviewed by Shawn, but they tell you an enormous amount about the world of finance and finance journalism.

For example, here we are in the middle of an article describing Gene and efficient markets.

…Understanding Fama’s evolving view of the market is one of the most valuable, practical guides for today’s investors. 
MORE: 20 top picks from 20 star investors 
Fama’s ideas may have received the ultimate validation, but they’re still highly controversial…. 
Well, they haven’t received the ultimate validation from the bots that run CNN money, that’s for sure!

…“The efficient-market hypothesis is the North Star for everything in finance,” says Asness. “One of the implications of his research is that every manager must be measured against a passive index to show if they’re really successful, and almost all fail over time." 
MORE: A decade of markets, mayhem, and investing 
In that sense, Fama is the intellectual father of today’s index fund industry. 
Only a decade? The comments just write themselves. 
…The overall market is a fabulous discounting machine, Fama contended, that handicaps future performance far more accurately than do active investors. The concept was shocking. It maintained that, contrary to virtually every other human endeavor, amateurs could easily beat professionals who pick individual stocks – in this case by merely following a passive index.
MORE: Where Bill Gross is putting his money 
Fama’s views quickly won acceptance among academics – and scorn from money managers. [my emphasis] "They brushed us off, and they still do,” says Fama. “I’d talk to reporters and they’d get it all backward.”…
Hmm. Something tells me Bill Gross isn’t putting his money in the Vanguard total market index, or even DFA core equity.  Are the links put in by a human with a devilish sense of humor? How can a computer program put in random links that are so hilarious, and so exactly opposite to the context? How can “more” link to things more exactly not “more?” A few more “mores” :
I saved the best for last:
…AQR Capital now incorporates momentum into the strategies behind many of its funds.
MORE: The Wall Street Stupidity Index
Perhaps the biggest challenge to the efficient-market hypothesis, however, came out of Fama’s own research….
Just sit back and enjoy that one.

Shawn’s final paragraph asks a deep question, made even deeper by the silly links that his publisher put in the article.
Is it possible, I ask him, that emotion and irrationality – the hallmarks of the behavioral school of finance – are far more powerful in explaining why folks are irrationally attracted to stock-picking managers than in explaining why stocks actually move? Fama shakes his head, chuckling. “I don’t know the reason why active management is so dominant,” he says. “At this stage, I find it completely puzzling.” And inefficient.
Gene once said something to the effect that belief in inefficiency is mostly marketing for active management fees. But there is a deep point here.  Rationalists like us shouldn’t just deplore something so persistent as folly (unless, I guess, perpetrated by the government). Active management must be serving some purpose to be so persistent in the marketplace… and in the ad machine on CNN’s website.

(Epliogue: Jonathan Berk and Rick Green’s papers start down a “rational ” path of understanding active managment, but that’s another story.) 
Learning the wrong lesson while waiting on hold

Learning the wrong lesson while waiting on hold

Health care policy debates seem to have become a war of anecdotes. Margaret Talbot of the New Yorker posted one titled “My canceled policy and my values” which is circulating the blogoshphere

… like many of the twelve million or so Americans who buy their own insurance, we received a letter from CareFirst in late October saying that our policy would be cancelled, because it didn’t conform to Affordable Care Act requirements. …I stopped procrastinating and got on the phone with CareFirst… First lesson learned: healthcare.gov is not the only balky system around.
I was on hold for forty-two minutes, mostly listening to an especially melancholy rendition of the “Moonlight” Sonata, before the agent who answered told me that she couldn’t help me with questions about individual policies, and, “with that being said,” CareFirst had been having “technical difficulties” all day. I waited another twenty minutes for a member-services representative who didn’t know why the company had increased my premium—maybe it was my age (fifty-two) or where I lived (Washington, D.C.)—or what about my policy didn’t meet the A.C.A. requirements. She transferred me to a third person (wait time fifteen minutes, listening material a jauntier, marimba-inflected Muzak), who told me that my premiums had most likely gone up thirty per cent owing to “the rising costs of health care” and then transferred me, without warning, to the D.C. Health Link, my state A.C.A. exchange. Second lesson learned: part of what is confusing and distressing about this process is that health-insurance companies don’t seem equipped, or maybe willing, to explain the implications of the new law to consumers. (Why raise a premium on a policy they must have known wouldn’t survive Obamacare?)
This reminds me of the hilarious “What if air travel worked like health care?” video that was circulating a few years ago.

Now how do you react to this atrocious level of service? What do you make of this experience vs., say Amazon.com, famous for short wait times and excellent service?

An economist makes the inference, “any company who treats me like this does not care about my business, and is not facing competition from upstart innovators. They must be massively regulated, licensed and protected from competition.”

New Yorker writers conclude
 The Affordable Care Act has not necessarily, at least not yet, made the workings of insurance companies any more transparent or accountable than they ever were.
i.e. that more regulation and protection from competition is going to bring 3 minute wait times, and cheerful informed staff. You know, the way the Affordable Shopping Act made the workings of internet retailers more transparent and accountable.

Her story is particularly poingnant.
I’ve had high blood pressure since I was in my thirties. I take ten milligrams of a generic beta blocker every morning, which has successfully kept my hypertension controlled. By doing so, I hope to prevent or postpone some of the possible consequences of hypertension—strokes, heart attacks—which are both debilitating and costly. That’s good preventive thinking for me, and good social policy, but it also means that I have a preëxisting condition
She is a classic case of someone who did everything right – she bought individual, non tax deductible, insurance, when young and healthy, so she would not lose coverage if she got older or sick. And Obamacare just destroyed that investment. Rather than outrage, however, she feels comforted that this theft may help those not so prescient:
So yes, I’ll subsidize someone else’s prenatal coverage, in a more effective way than I’ve been doing by default under the current system, in which too many pregnant women show up in emergency rooms without having had such care, creating problems for themselves and their babies, and all sorts of costs for taxpayers. And I’ll remember to be relieved that my own access to health care is guaranteed. But they had better work out the problems with the A.C.A.; if they don’t, and it doesn’t fulfill its promise of insuring the uninsured, I’m really going to feel like a chump.
When you get that feeling, you will have company. But don’t feel bad. Many a good free-marketer, in their youth, made similar mistakes. We all have values about helping people, and eventually we learn the hard lessons of cause and effect, and what actually works to that end.
Fama Nobel En Espanol

Fama Nobel En Espanol

Pedro Cervera kindly translated my short piece on Gene Fama’s Nobel prize, which will appear in “Estrategia Financiera” next month:

Eugene Fama: Mercados eficientes, primas de riesgo y el premio Nobel.

En 1970, Gene Fama definió que un mercado era “informacionalmente eficiente” si los precios incorporaban en cada momento la información disponible relativa a los valores futuros.
“Un mercado en el que los precios reflejan la totalidad de la información existente es denominado eficiente “[Fama, 1970]. 
….

para el resto, haga clic aquí para un pdf

For the rest go here for a pdf (I don’t speak Spanish and gave up trying to get accents right in blogger!)